September 2011
The world has a growing need for safe assets. The financial crisis of 2007-08 showed that financial markets can be enormously volatile as investors migrate from one asset to another in search of safety. But Europe’s fragmented sovereign debt markets cannot offer the quantity of safe assets that financial institutions demand and thus cannot effectively compete with U.S. Treasuries, which benefit from a U.S. consolidated market.
This situation led to two severe problems. First, it created a diabolic loop European financial systems and states. An important source of the fiscal problems affecting many European states is the perceived need by the market to back up weakened national banking systems. In turn European banks are in distress because they hold large quantities of debt from sovereigns facing challenging fiscal outlooks. This situation has multiple origins but essentially banks have incentives to hold sovereign debt as it offers clear regulatory advantages, and it is in turn beneficial for governments to fund themselves through their own national banking system. Removing the perverse incentives that tie banks and sovereigns in this diabolic loop is essential to remove a key source of contagion. Breaking the loop requires removing the distortion at its root: sovereign bonds must be assigned both capital risk weights and haircuts for discount operations with the European Central Bank (ECB) that reflect the risks they represent both to the banks and the ECB.
The second severe problem is that, in the absence of a European safe bond, the bonds of some sovereigns at Europe’s center have satisfied the demand for safe assets. In times of crisis, capital flows from the periphery to the center; in boom phases, capital flows from the center to the periphery. These alternating capital flows between searching for “yield” and searching for “safe haven”, generate large capital account imbalances in the Euro area, with associated changes in relative prices and potential disruptions in asset markets.
To address these three shortcomings in the design of the Eurozone, we propose a two-pronged approach: (i) redesign bank regulation and ECB policy so that both will take into account the risk of sovereign bonds, and (ii) supply a large amount of euro-wide bonds as close as possible to being risk-free, that is, the creation of European Safe Bonds (ESB), which we will refer to as ESBies for short. These new instruments would be European, being issued by a newly developed European Debt Agency (EDA) in accordance with existing European Treaties, and would not require more fiscal integration than that already in place. They would be Safe being designed to minimize default risk, issued in euros and benefiting from the ECB’s anti-inflation commitment; they would be liquid as they would be issued in large volumes and serve as safe haven for investors seeking a negative correlation with other yields. They would be Bonds, freely traded in markets, and held by banks, investors and central banks to satisfy the demand for safe assets described above.
How would ESBies work? A new European Debt Agency would buy the sovereign bonds of member nations according to the relative size of the different member States. The EDA would passively hold these bonds as assets in its balance sheet, and use them as collateral to issue two securities. The first security, the ESBies, would be a senior claim on the payments from the sovereign bonds held in the portfolio. The second security would have a junior claim on these payments — that is, it would be first in line to absorb whatever loss is realized in the pool of sovereign bonds that serve as collateral for these issues. That is, any failure by a sovereign state to honor in full its debts would be absorbed by the holders of the junior tranche security, not by the EDA, any Eurozone entity or the European Union. Both tranches — ESBies and the junior tranche — would be sold to willing investors in the market. Investors who want to hedge (or even speculate) on the ability of European member states to pay their debt would derive substantial benefits from trading these junior tranches. Investors seeking a safe asset denominated in a stable currency would benefit from holding ESBies.
The ESBies would be the preferential holding of banks and the preferential tool for monetary policy by the ECB. The ECB would grant strict preferential treatment to ESBies, accepting them as its main form of collateral in repurchase (repo) transactions and discounting operations. Because of the fixed weights in the ESBies, this would be consistent with conventional monetary policy, where open market operations would trade money for the safe ESBies without the ECB incurring credit risk or having large changes in the composition of its balance sheet. Second, banking regulators, including Basel, would give the ESBies a zero risk weight but would not do so automatically to other sovereign bonds. Some may deserve it, but others may not, and their risk weight should be attributed in a similar way to corporate bonds, depending on the default risk of the respective country.
Some benefits of our proposal stem from changes in bank regulation and ECB policy; others stem from the introduction of ESBies, and still others from the interaction of the two.